You cannot control inflation with tax cuts
Sound macroeconomic management and nurturing the tax base, so as to retain fiscal firepower, are key
Now that the Union government has reduced its levies on petrofuels, are we out of the woods on inflation? The basic thing to understand about inflation is that it is a function of a whole lot of things other than taxes and subsidies, and that offering tax cuts and subsidies is more politics than economics.
India collects very little of the income generated every year as tax. Tax/GDP is about 17% of GDP for the Centre and the states combined, and about two-thirds of that comes as indirect taxes. The good thing about the new method of presenting our national income accounts is that there is transparency as to how much of our GDP is value added and how much, tax on goods and services, net of subsidy.
Some Love It Hot
Net tax was 7.7% of GDP in 2014-15, and the annual inflation that year, as measured by change in the Consumer Price Index, was 5.9%. Net tax rose to 8.6% of GDP by 2019-20, inflation fell to 4.8%. In 2021-22, net tax/GDP rose further to 9.7%, but inflation, at 5.4%, was lower than in 2014-15.
Changing a rate of tax here, extending some subsidy there and restricting exports to enhance domestic availability — these serve to signal to voters that the government is at work. Containing inflation calls for macroeconomic management, with regulation of the supply of some key essentials playing a role in the short run.
Inflation can come from either excess demand or supply disruptions, or a combination of the two. The way to curb excess demand is to raise interest rates, for the non-government sector, and for the government to exercise fiscal restraint and not buy up more goods and services than the private sector could spare, just because the state can borrow at the cheapest rate in the economy.
Before turning to measures to tame inflation, let us understand that some influential people gain a lot from inflation that is elevated, but not yet out of control. Inflation is a boon for those who carry a large burden of debt.
The loan amount is fixed, and does not go up with the rate of inflation. As a proportion of their income, debt would come down, unless their income growth turns negative.
The government, of course, is the biggest beneficiary of inflation. Nominal GDP would grow faster than if inflation were tepid. As a proportion of GDP, the debt the government has to service would come down.
The other big beneficiary is industry with a high debt load and relatively steady demand for its output. Energy, whether transport fuels or electricity, face inelastic demand, apart from basic staples.
Inflation sorts people into two kinds: those whose incomes grow, along with inflation, and those whose incomes stay constant (or even disappear, as when their jobs and businesses fall prey to inflation). Organised sector workers see their income catch up with inflation, via things like dearness allowance or handsome raises and bonuses. Unorganised sector workers, and often, their employers, see their incomes stagnate.
When income lags the cost of things you consume, real consumption comes down. Another way of describing this is that there is a shift in the income distribution away from those whose incomes lag prices, towards those with pricing power. This is what justifies special taxes on windfall profits.
Inflation affects the exchange rate. The economy in which prices rise faster than in another will see its currency depreciate against the currency of the economy with lower erosion of purchasing power. Exchange rates are affected not just by inflation or interest rate differentials, but also by perceptions of relative risk and growth potential. Right now, the dollar has risen against practically all other currencies, so, even as the rupee has lost value against the dollar, its trade weighted exchange rate against a basket of currencies has declined less. But imports whose price is designated in dollars will see their rupee price go up. Inflation, in this manner, can reinforce itself via the exchange rate and the cost of imports.
Industry that has huge external borrowings has reason to fear inflation and depreciation of the currency. Their debt servicing burden in rupees would grow.
Don’t Choke Growth
Inflation arising from supply disruptions should be allowed to feed through the system, to let people curb consumption and find substitutes. Only when the price rises of the first round begin to feed into a generalised cost increase should higher rates of interest curb demand.
Repressing fuel prices by forcing public sector oil marketing companies to sell below cost does threefold harm: it thwarts possible energy efficiency and demand reduction; it makes India look a bit like China, with private fuel retail business made to suffer on account of political expedience; and it eats into taxable profits.
The poor need growth, not just stable prices. So, in an economy like India’s, monetary and fiscal policy must maintain a fine balance between growth and inflation. Eating into taxable profits by curbing exports drains fiscal capacity and private investment, both vital for growth. Reducing indirect taxes also hurts fiscal firepower, but, at least, shores up real consumption. Subsuming fuel taxes into GST is the right step.
Dear Prudent Political-Economist Editor,
As I read the head, synopsis, cutline and the first paragraph of your economist-leader opinion, considering your uncompromising zeal and commitment to the cause of citizens and democracy, growth and economic-political-social development of the country defined through your journalistic leadership in esteemed The Economic Times, IMPRI, a think tank for proactive, independent, non-partisan, and policy-based research in New Delhi & other reputed forums, I must write that the lily-livered cabinet, Government of India and fellow JNUite(your junior), Ms Nirmala Sitharaman, the Finance Minister of India neither understand economics nor seek advice of most prudent Political-Economist Editor like you and others in 2022.
Thus, the FM of India and our PM disgracefully and foolishly continue to cheat us/citizens by playing politics in place of practicing economics of high standard.
Also, the manner in which massive amounts of money, time, and energy is wasted in missteps and misgovernance with propaganda results in unavoidable disasters ie; extended slowdown in economic activities.
I must reiterate the fact that this is not the first time you explained inflation from an economic perspective! If I as an ordinary reader can understand lucid explanations of how inflation works, how to contain inflation with macroeconomic management etc, why can't the FM make an effort to understand the huge losses we citizens have from such faulty economic policies?
I assert my point, 'all knowledgeable, rational, well-aware and democratic persons know our PM having a degree in entire Political Science does not understand E of Economics'.
Here comes the main point, under 'Some like it Hot' head, the second paragraph reflects terrible uncertainty and indecision even if Modi and his coward Ministers attempt to signal voters that the Govt is at work.
Ultimately, the most reliable & apt advice stated in the last two concluding paragraphs questioning the Govt of India's incapacity to act, to subsume fuel taxes into the GST and give a fair chance to revenue collection and help industry consumers seems like a distant reality.
Thank you for writing and highlighting time and again, the colossal failure of the Government of India, 'Think long-term, act short-term' in the case of monetary and fiscal policy under the worst economic and financial crisis of India opinion placed with your ever smiling, bright picture in the IMPRI document and firstly, in The Economic Times newspaper.
And here, the image has these colourful, emoji balloons with smiley expression conveying the message of politics at work further ruining the economy hugely infected by disordered uses of power, lust and greed under PM Modi's leadership.
Your ordinary, well-informed reader and creative soul,
Vandana